saving rate increased and in consequence growth slowed ( Steindl
1982 ); in 1980 to 1982 there was a deep recession. In addition to
these influences from the demand side there were, moreover, large
tax reductions in the 80s without any reduction in expenditure
which was boosted by the demands of the military sector; the
implication of this was that even a high level of employment would
not have sufficed to eliminate the budget deficit. The paradoxon
was that the business community which had denounced relatively
small deficits in the past now accepted monstrous ones without
serious resistence since they were caused by current tax cuts.
Apres nous le deluge!
What made this debt policy so unKeynesian and so dangerous was its
coincidence with a high real rate of interest in the 80s.
In view of the large role which interest policy played and of the
fact that it is a function of power of pressure groups in society
we may ask whether there may not be a sequence of action and
reaction, of alternating policy modes here,too. There exists
evidently an opposition of interests of creditor and debtor in our
economy. Formerly the debtors were prominently represented by
industry and their interests were opposed by the banks which
allied themselves to the rentier. One can find examples in history
when there was an alternation of the preponderance of one or the
other of those groups ( Bhaduri-Steindl 1985 ). Finance came to
dominate with the imperial ascent of Britain and home industry was
relatively neglected; in the 30s industry gained renewed
importance by means of protection while after world war II the
influence of the banks gradually increased up to a climax in the
era of monetarism.
Today the distinction between the interests of industry and
finance has been blurred since many large industrial concerns have