market. In this way the reformers hope to unleash a process of
accumulation set in motion by the activities of many new small and
independent enterprises as well as of the managers of existing
large enterprises which to a large extent are to be freed of the
shackles of burocratic controls. Once a certain reluctance owing
to doubts and distrust of the policy is overcome it is very likely
that a certain number of people will seize the novel opportunity
to earn something by their efforts. How strongly people will
respond depends, it is true, on their "economic culture"
( "Wirtschaftsgeist" Max Weber would have called it ) which makes
them more or less inclined to risk taking and entrepreneurial
activity ( Armenians as compared with Turks? ). However, some
response can be expected everywhere and with success the movement
will spread. A major difficulty is the provision of infrastructure
and all the outside help which a small entrepreneur needs in order
to prosper ( transport for the peasant to bring his goods to the
market, materials for the craftsman who offers repair service ),
in fact all the things which are usually quoted as conditions for
"external economies". Here is a great task for the economic
politicians and the administration on which they have to rely.
If the reform succeeds the resulting process will basically
ressemble a large extended boom in a capitalist country except
that it will almost certainly lead sooner or later to an excess of
effective demand, a genuine demand inflation which in capitalist
countries exists only in the imagination of economists who use the
bogey of inflation in order to justify restrictive banking
policies.In capitalism in fact the boom just as often is broken by
the appearance of excess capacity as by bottlenecks on the supply
side, but even in the latter case it does not lead to demand
inflation because the restrictive tendencies inherent in developed